Can hospitals provide better care for less money? The assumption that they can is baked into the Affordable Care Act.
Historically, hospital productivity has grown much more slowly than the overall economy, if at all. That’s true of health care in general. Productivity — in this case the provision of care per dollar and the improvements in health to which it leads — has never grown as quickly as would be required for hospitals to keep pace with scheduled cuts to reimbursements from Medicare.
But
to finance coverage expansion, the Affordable Care Act made a big bet
that hospitals could provide better care for less money from Medicare.
Hospitals that cannot become more productive quickly enough will be
forced to cut back. If the past is any guide, they may do so in ways
that harm patients.
The Obamacare gamble that hospitals can become much more productive conflicts with a famous theory of why health care costs rise. William Baumol, a New York University economist, called it the “cost disease.” (He wrote a book about it by that title; I blogged on it as I read it if you’d like to quickly get the gist.)
This
theory asserts that productivity growth in health care is inherently
low for the same reason it is in education: Productivity-enhancing
technologies cannot easily replace human doctors or teachers. In
contrast with, say, manufacturing — a sector in which machines have
rapidly taken over functions that workers used to do, and have done them
better and more cheaply — there are, at least for the time being, far
fewer machines that can step in and outperform doctors, nurses or other
health sector jobs.
But
a new study casts doubt on that theory and suggests Obamacare’s bet may
indeed pay off. The study, published in Health Affairs by John Romley, Dana Goldman and Neeraj Sood,
found that hospitals’ productivity has grown more rapidly in recent
years than in prior ones. Hospitals are providing better care at a
faster rate than growth in the payments they receive from Medicare,
according to the study.
This
is both good news for patients and good news for the financing of the
health reform law, which assumes hospitals will become significantly
more productive. This bet is built into a schedule of reductions in the
rate of growth in Medicare payments to hospitals. According to the law,
those rates are to be reduced commensurate with the productivity growth of the overall economy. The only way for hospitals to keep up is if their productivity rises just as quickly.
The
cost disease theory says it can’t be done. This, according to the
theory, is what causes health care spending growth to outpace that of
the overall economy.
Computers,
cellphones, televisions — over the years they’ve all gotten better and
cheaper. High productivity growth in such sectors — not mirrored in
health care — leads to wage growth in those sectors. Higher wages
provide more resources to spend on goods and services. Because health
care is valuable, we use those resources to pay health care workers
more, too, to keep them from doing something else. This helps explain
why health care spending outpaces economic growth: We keep paying more
for health care (through growing wages) without getting more (because of
low productivity growth).
Not all economists
find every detail of the cost disease theory compelling. Some have
argued, for example, that it gives short shrift to ways in which the
quality of care changes, along with its price. Heart attack treatment
certainly costs more today than a decade ago. Perhaps it’s also better.
The acceptance of inevitably low health care productivity growth also
troubles some economists.
Amitabh Chandra, a Harvard economist, is one of them: “In Baumol’s view, as long as there is a steady stream of innovation in sectors others than health care — from cars to computers to everything on Amazon — we’ll be able to spend even more on health care, despite its jaundiced productivity growth. But if productivity in health care improves, too, then think about how much more health care we’ll be able to afford.”
If the cost disease theory’s premise of low health care productivity growth holds, then the idea of tying reductions in the growth of Medicare payments to hospitals to economic growth — as the Affordable Care Act does — spells trouble.
Amitabh Chandra, a Harvard economist, is one of them: “In Baumol’s view, as long as there is a steady stream of innovation in sectors others than health care — from cars to computers to everything on Amazon — we’ll be able to spend even more on health care, despite its jaundiced productivity growth. But if productivity in health care improves, too, then think about how much more health care we’ll be able to afford.”
If the cost disease theory’s premise of low health care productivity growth holds, then the idea of tying reductions in the growth of Medicare payments to hospitals to economic growth — as the Affordable Care Act does — spells trouble.
The
findings by Mr. Romley and colleagues from the Schaeffer Center for
Health Policy and Economics at the University of Southern California are
a hopeful sign this need not happen. A strength of the study is it
incorporated an aspect of the quality of care into its measure of
productivity: whether the care received kept more patients alive and out
of the hospital for at least 30 days. The findings were qualitatively
similar for shorter (two weeks) or longer windows (one year). This
distinguishes it from other approaches that measure productivity
according to how many procedures a hospital can do per dollar, but not
how well they do them.
According to the analysis, productivity fell for heart attack and heart failure
patients between 2002 and 2005, after which it began to rise. For
hospital care for all three conditions examined — heart attacks, heart
failure and pneumonia — productivity growth accelerated after 2007. By 2011 it was more than 14 percent over the level it had been in 2002.
The
source of the broadest optimism from the study: Hospital productivity
increased in the most recent years faster than that of the overall
economy.
Though
the study is an important one, we should interpret it with some
caution. It examined only one measure of productivity; it examined only
three conditions in Medicare patients; and it examined data only through
2011. More studies like this one — but using different methods and more
recent data — could confirm or refute these findings.
Nevertheless,
for decades the conventional wisdom has been that hospitals — and the
health care sector in general — could not become more productive,
explaining its growing expense. This new study suggests that such a cost
disease may not be as inherent as once believed — and that the health care law’s cuts to Medicare are not as risky a bet as they once seemed.
Austin Frakt is a health economist with several governmental and academic affiliations. He blogs at The Incidental Economist, and you can follow him on Twitter at @afrakt.
source
source
No comments:
Post a Comment